1
The Future Monetary Policy
The
mid-1960s Henry Levin film Genghis Khan featured a rugged-looking Omar
Sharif
in
the title
role playing opposite Robert Morley, at his plump and pompous best as
the Chin
emperor
Wang
Wei-shao. One of the film’s early scenes shows the exquisitely attired
Morley,
calligraphy
brush in
hand, elegantly composing a poem. With an ethereal self-assurance born
of
unquestioning
confidence in the divinely ordained course of worldly affairs, Morley
explains
that
the
poem’s purpose is to express his displeasure at the Mongol barbarians
who have
lately been
creating
a disturbance on the Chin empire’s western frontier, and, by so doing,
cause
them to
desist.
Today
expressions of intentions by leaders of the world’s major central banks
typically
have
immediate repercussions in financial markets, and perhaps more broadly
as well.
Does
Chairman
Greenspan believe that the U.S.
business expansion has advanced to the point where a
new round
of wage inflation may be imminent? Did President Duisenberg imply that
because
Article
103 of the Maastricht Treaty refers to Article 102a, and both Article
102a and
Article 105
refer to
Article 2, Europe’s chronic high
unemployment
may be a proper object of policy concern
for the
European Central Bank after all? Is Governor Hayami content to allow Japan
to languish
in a
slump for yet another half-decade? Central bankers’ public utterances
and
other, more subtle
signals
on such questions regularly move prices and yields in the financial
markets,
and these
financial
variables in turn affect nonfinancial economic activity in a variety of
ways.
Indeed, a
widely
shared opinion today is that central banks need not actually do
anything. With
a clear
enough
statement of intentions, “the markets will do the work for them.”
In truth,
the ability of central banks to affect the evolution of prices and
output in
the.2
nonfinancial
economy has always been something of a mystery. It is not that there
are no
good
accounts
of how this influence might arise. There are many. The problem is
rather that
each such
story,
while plausible enough at first or even second thought , turns out to
depend on
one or
another
of a series of by-now familiar fictions: Households and firms need
currency to
purchase
goods and
services. Banks can issue only reserve-bearing liabilities. No nonbank
financial
institutions
create credit. And so on.
This
central mystery notwithstanding, at the practical level there is today
little
doubt that a
country’s
monetary policy not only can but does largely determine the evolution
of its
general
price
level over the medium to longer run, and almost as little doubt that
monetary
policy exerts
significant
influence over aspects of real economic activity, like output and
employment,
over the
short to
medium run. The assumptions necessary to explain in simple terms how
this
happens are
fictions,
but they are useful fictions. Apart from purely empirical matters of
magnitude
and
timing,
the live question today is which set of fictions (that is, which model)
provides the most
useful
description of the underlying causal process.
Circumstances
change over time, however, and when they do the fictions that once
described
matters adequately may no longer do so. A later scene in Levin’s film
shows
Morley
still
magnificently clothed but now lying in the mud, face blackened by
gunpowder, in
the wake of
a Mongol
attack on the Chin capital. There may well have been an earlier time
when the
might of
the Chin
empire was such that the mere suggestion of willingness to use it was
sufficient
to make
potential
invaders reconsider and withdraw. But by Wang Wei-shao’s day that time
had
evidently
passed..3
The
object of this paper is to consider the possible future of central
banks’
monetary
policymaking
— say, over the next quarter-century — in light of several significant
aspects
of
how the
circumstances that bear on this process have been changing over the
past
quarter-century.
Simply
extrapolating in this way the recent development of financial market
institutions
and
practices is, of course, no substitute for actually knowing what lies
ahead,
but doing so at
least
provides some observationally grounded basis for thinking about the
future. The
point is to
work out
the implications for central banks’ ability to carry out monetary
policy. The question
of
what to
do in response to those implications, should they indeed materialize,
lies
beyond the scope
of this
paper..
The
Central Bank as Monopolist
The
easiest way to see why the influence of central banks over nonfinancial
economic
activity
is such a puzzle is to consider their small size, and the even smaller
size of
their monetary
policy
operations, in relation to the economies that they supposedly
influence. In the
United
States,
for example, a year’s production of final output is more than $8.5
trillion.
Including the
production
and exchange of intermediate goods and services, the volume of
nonfinancial
transactions
that take place in the course of a year is several times $8.5 trillion.
Yet the
total
volume of
reserves that banks and other financial institutions maintain with the
Federal
Reserve
System is
less than $50 billion. And the difference between 2% per annum growth
of
reserves
(which
most observers would consider a tight monetary policy, all else equal)
and 10%
per annum
reserves
growth (which most would think highly expansionary) is whether the
Federal
Reserve
buys $1
billion or $5 billion of securities over an entire year.
The more
typical way of looking at the central bank’s influence over the
nonfinancial
economy
side-steps these quantitative disparities by focusing on market
interest rates.
Firms as
well as
households rely on borrowing to finance their spending for many
purposes, from
putting
up
factories and houses to buying new cars and refrigerators, to paying
college
tuitions or simply
taking
vacations. It is not surprising that the cost of financing these
expenditures
therefore affects
the
willingness to undertake them. Moreover, in many cases where spending
does not
rely on
borrowing,
interest rates and expected asset returns more generally represent the
relevant
opportunity
cost. Hence the ability to affect interest rates and asset returns is
in turn
sufficient to
enable
the central bank to affect spending in nonfinancial markets..
But this
line of thinking only pushes the anomaly to be explained into a
different
arena:
How,
exactly, does the central bank affect interest rates? Here again, even
a quick
glance at the
relevant
magnitudes highlights the problem. In the United States, for example,
the
outstanding
volume of
securities issued directly by the U.S. Treasury is $3.7 trillion.
Including
issues of U.S.
Government-sponsored
and guaranteed agencies brings the overall size of the government
securities
market to $7.1 trillion. Further including privately issued but
publicly traded
debt
instruments
that are close substitutes for government securities of one maturity or
other
brings the
total
size of the U.S.
fixed-income securities market to $13.6 trillion. In 1998 alone,
insurance
companies
bought (on net) $101 billion of securities in this market, pension
funds bought
$186
billion,
banks bought $82 billion, and households liquidated $57 billion of
securities
that they
already
owned. Gross trading volume is typically in the hundreds of billions of
dollars
daily, and it
is not
unusual for a single private firm to buy or sell more than $1 billion
of
securities in a single
transaction.
Yet it is somehow supposed to make a major difference, for the entire
level and
structure
of prices and yields in this nearly $14 trillion market, whether the
Federal
Reserve buys
or sells
$1 billion or $5 billion of securities over an entire year.
As Table
1 shows, a similar disparity between the magnitude of central banks’
monetary
policy
operations and the size of the markets in which they operate is
characteristic
of other
economies
as well. Going on to consider currency substitution — in other words,
the fact
that for
many
investors a debt security denominated in a foreign currency is an
actual or
potential
portfolio
substitute for a comparable debt security denominated in the currency
of the
investor’s
country
of residence — only makes the disparity all that much greater from the
perspective of any.6
individual
central bank (though not for all central banks taken together, as if
they acted
in
concert).
Considering equity securities as actual or potential substitutes for
debt
securities makes
the
disparity greater still, from the perspective of either a single
central bank
or all taken together.
(The
volume of equity securities held in U.S. markets was $15.4
trillion at
1998 yearend market
prices.)
The
standard explanation for central banks’ ability to affect such large
markets
through
such
small operations is that transactions by the central bank are
fundamentally
different from
transactions
by private market participants. When a central bank buys securities, it
makes
payment
by increasing the reserve account of the seller’s bank, thereby
increasing the
total volume
of
reserves that the banking system collectively holds. When a central
bank sells
securities, it
receives
payment by reducing the reserve account of the buyer’s bank, thereby
reducing
the total
volume of
reserves. No other market participant can either increase or reduce the
total
volume of
reserves.
The central bank is a monopoly supplier (and withdrawer) of reserves.
This
monopoly position matters because under any of a variety of conceptions
of the
monetary
policy process, banks and other financial institutions must hold
reserves with
the central
bank in
order to carry out the economic functions that households and firms
look to
them to
perform.
The traditional “money view” of monetary policy begins with households’
and
firms’
demand
for bank-issued money, against which banks must, by law, hold reserves
(usually
specified
as some
set fraction of each bank’s outstanding deposits). When the monopolist
central
bank
reduces
the supply of reserves, banks therefore must reduce the amount of money
that
they supply
to
households and firms. As households and firms compete with one another
to hold
the now.7
shrunken
supply of money, their individual efforts to sell securities for money
cannot
produce any
more
money but do, collectively, drive the price of securities down — that
is, they
drive interest
rates up.
The
“credit view” of monetary policy focuses on a different aspect of the
relationship
between
the financial and nonfinancial worlds, but for this purpose it leads to
the
same conclusion.
Households
and firms look to banks to extend loans (credit). Banks can do so only
to the
extent
that they
simultaneously create money — in other words, the respective totals on
the two
sides of
any
bank’s balance sheet must always remain equal. But if banks must create
money
in order to
advance
credit, and creating more money means requiring more reserves, the
central
bank’s role
as
monopoly supplier of reserves is again crucial. When the central bank
reduces
the supply of
reserves,
banks have to cut back on their lending, and the loan market will clear
at a
higher
interest
rate.
Some
observers of financial markets, mindful of the intertemporal arbitrage
conditions that
relate
the pricing of short- and long-term securities, attempt to skirt this
kind of
reasoning and
argue
that the central bank can affect interest rates on all but the
shortest-term
instruments — and
hence can
influence nonfinancial economic activity — merely by signaling its
intention to
change
the
prevailing level of short-term rates in the future. Hence a signal of
intentions is sufficient to
influence
nonfinancial activity as well. The basic idea underlying this argument
is that,
apart from
whatever
risk and liquidity premia the market assesses, the yield on a two-year
bond
should equal
the
(geometric) average of the currently prevailing one-year yield and the
expected
one-year yield
a year in
the future. If the central bank does or says something that changes
expectations about.8
next
year’s short-term rate, it thereby moves today’s long-term rate. And
since many
if not most
kinds of
spending by households and firms are more sensitive to long- (or at
least
medium-) than
short-term
interest rates, doing so thereby affects the nonfinancial economy as
well. It
is just this
kind of
reasoning that people have in mind when they speak of letting the
markets do
the central
bank’s
work for it.
But this
logic makes sense only if the central bank can credibly affect widely
shared
expectations
of future short-term interest rates, and unless most market
participants are
prepared
to be
fooled most of the time, that in turn makes sense only if the central
bank can
indeed affect
actual
short-term interest rates when the time comes. And that ability, in
turn,
relies on some
process
like the ones described by the familiar “money view” and “credit view.”
At the
end of the
logical
chain, the central bank’s role as the monopoly supplier of reserves is
essential.
Threats
to the Relevance of the Central Bank’s Monopoly
It may
seem odd, at the close of the twentieth century, to suggest that the
ability of
central
banks to
control or at least shape the development of their respective economies
stands
at risk.
Two
decades ago chronic price inflation had reached levels that profoundly
disturbed not only
many
economists and public policy mavens but also much of the general public
in most
of the
world’s
industrialized countries. In some countries prices threatened to rise
even
faster, perhaps
explosively.
Today inflation is negligible in most industrialized countries, and
almost
everyone
awards
central banks primary responsibility for this dramatic reversal. Over
just the
last decade
many
large economies have also experienced reduced instability of output and
employment, and.9
many
people credit central banks for this accomplishment too. In short, it
has been
a good era for
monetary
policy.
But
financial institutions and financial practices are changing, and the
direction
of many of
these
changes spells trouble for the ability of central banks to carry out
their
monetary policy
responsibilities
effectively. The heart of the matter lies in the way central banks
influence
market
interest
rates. In most countries there is no challenge to the central bank’s
position
as the
monopolist
controlling the supply of reserves. Rather, the question is whether
that
monopoly will
remain
relevant.
Erosion
of the Demand for Bank Money. Being a monopolist is of little value if
nobody
needs, or
even wants, to have whatever the monopoly is of. The “money view” of
monetary
policy
begins from the assumption that households and firms need money, for
transactions
purposes
or portfolio purposes or both, and goes on to exploit the fact that
banks can
create
money
only if they have the reserves they are required to hold in parallel
with their
outstanding
deposits.
(In the United
States
today, for example, banks are required to hold reserves against
forms of
deposits used to settle transactions but not against other kinds of
deposits,
like savings
accounts
and CDs.) That is what makes the central bank’s monopoly over the
supply of
reserves
relevant.
In recent
years, however, the development of new technologies has advanced to the
point
where
there are a variety of visible alternatives to conventional bank money
as a
means of
undertaking
transactions, and in some cases even of settling transactions.
Especially with
the
introduction
of third-party credit cards in the 1960s, and increasingly so since
then,
economists’.10
standard
“cash in advance” models have no longer borne much relation to
arrangements for
purchasing
goods and services in the modern economy. For most items, neither cash
in one’s
pocket
nor an adequate balance in one’s checking account is necessary at the
time of
purchase.
More
recent improvements like electronic cash, and “smart cards” (which have
now
made
significant
inroads in such countries as Germany,
France and Japan
and are just coming into use
in
the United
States),
have accentuated this trend.
The
reason central banks’ influence over interest rates has survived these
developments is
that
money, in the conventional sense, has remained necessary for ultimate
settlement of these
transactions.
The merchants who accept Visa or Mastercharge cards need to be paid,
and that
still
means having conventional money deposited into their bank accounts. And
once a
month
individuals
who use these credit cards must make a payment by transferring
conventional
money
out of
their bank accounts (unless they borrow the money that is due — about
which
more
below).
For reasons well described by familiar models of the “transactions” and
“precautionary”
demand
for money, the ability to buy goods and services at will throughout the
month
but then
settle
all of the transactions together at month’s end may well reduce the
typical
household or
firm’s
average need to hold money balances, but it does not eliminate this
need. Hence
banks’
demand
for reserves may be smaller, for a given fractional reserve
requirement, but it
remains as
well. As
is well known, the central bank’s ability to carry out monetary policy
depends
not on the
size but
on the stability of the demand for reserves.
The
future may be different, however, in either of two ways that bear on
just this
question.
First,
some types of “smart cards” — for example, the single-vendor
advance-payment
cards.11
already
put into circulation by many telephone service providers (this practice
is now
especially
widespread
in Japan), or by
the New York
subway system —
could develop into genuine private
monies.
In New York,
for example, the Metropolitan Transit Authority has made several
attempts,
to date largely unsuccessful, to persuade city-area merchants to accept
MTA
smart
cards in
payment for purchases. Even if such cards were to gain acceptance, as
long as
issuers
like the
MTA in turn settled with merchants by transferring balances at banks,
then in
effect these
cards
would be no different from today’s Visa or Mastercharge cards. But it
is easy
to imagine
how — 25
years in the future, after acceptance of such cards had become
sufficiently
widespread
— firms
would simply accept, and swap, balances on the MTA’s books. (Hence the
form of
“smart
card” in question here differs importantly from the MONDEX card, in
which the
issuer is
always a
bank and the redeemer is always a bank.)
Such a
system would still involve the use of bank money, but only as the
initial base
of the
value
chain. The customer who buys a “smart card” from a nonbank firm would
presumably pay
for it
using a bank check or cash. But to the extent that third parties were
willing
to accept
balances
on the nonbank firm’s books in payment for their own transactions,
there would
be no
need for
the firm that issues the card to maintain bank balances to back up in
full its
corresponding
liability. At that point, nonfinancial transactions made by swapping
balances
on
that
firm’s books would take place independently of any new, contemporary
use of
bank money
(or
cash), and hence independently of any need for reserves at the central
bank.
Needless
to say, not all nonfinancial firms are equally plausible candidates to
undertake
this
activity. Nonfinancial firms typically do not have access to the safety
net
that central banks,.12
deposit
insurance funds and other government agencies normally maintain for
banks.
Hence a
customer
who buys this kind of “smart card” would have to have confidence in the
permanence
and
soundness the firm issuing it. Moreover, telephone companies and other
widely
used utilities
have the
further advantage that nearly everyone buys services from them on an
ongoing
basis.
Even if
customers bought a telephone company’s advance-payment card and then
found that
no
merchants
would accept it, they could always use the balance on it (which, to
recall,
represents
the
company’s liability to them) to pay their telephone bill.
1
Such a
development would involve advancing these card systems, or other forms
of
e-cash,
to the point where they would provide not merely payment but also
settlement.
At the
moment
this prospect is hardly imminent. But with rapidly advancing data
processing
and
encryption
technology, and the gradual disappearance of the visible distinction
between
banks and
other
businesses (importantly including nonfinancial firms) in the public’s
perception, the prospect
is far
from inconceivable a quarter-century in the future. As long as taking
deposits
and providing
payment
services is a source of profit for banks, bank customers — like
telephone
companies,
New York’s MTA, or the merchants whom the
MTA would like to induce to use its cards —
have an
incentive to recoup some of their costs by undertaking a form of this
activity
themselves.
And to
the extent that they can pass on some of what they recoup to their own
customers,
individuals
will have an incentive to use these alternative payment vehicles just
as
nonbank firms
will have
an incentive to provide them.
How would
central banks respond? One possibility would be to engage in a
regulatory
race, in
which the monetary authorities in each country continually expanded the
coverage of.13
reserve
requirements to blanket new issuers of what amounts to money, while the
issuers
of
private
monies responded by continually changing their product in order to
evade each new
set of
expanded
requirements. Experience — for example, that of the Federal Reserve
System in
the
1960s,
when the new instruments in question were Eurodollar deposits and
negotiable
CDs —
suggests
that this is a race the central banks might well lose.
If so,
what would then be left to the central bank would be its control over
the
remainder
of the
monetary base, the great majority of which in most countries is not
bank
reserves but
outstanding
currency. Although monetary theorists frequently write as if control
over
“central
bank
money” were all there was to monetary policy, and sometimes point to
empirical
correlations
between a
country’s monetary base and its income or prices, currency has become
increasingly
irrelevant
to legal, domestic transactions. Moreover, the observed correlations
between
growth
of
currency and growth of either income or prices mostly reflect the fact
that
central banks
normally
just accommodate whatever the public’s demand for currency happens to
be. If
advances
in electronic technology facilitate the use of private nonbank monies,
outside
the scope
of the
central bank’s reserve requirements, neither the nickels and dimes used
in
vending machines
nor the
$100 bills used to pay drug dealers will be sufficient to preserve the
efficacy
of monetary
policy.
Cooperation
of a central bank’s government can also be an important part of the
story.
Governments
typically make payments, for purposes of income transfers as well as
purchases
of
goods and
services, using deposit accounts at banks. It is fair to assume that
they will
continue to
do so.
Governments can also easily require that all tax payments be in the
form of
bank money.14
(or an
equivalent that is settled in bank money). Hence one sector of the
economy — a
large one
in many
countries — is a potentially captive market for this purpose. But the
government sector
is not
what most people have in mind when they worry about the central bank’s
ability
to
influence
nonfinancial economic activity. If private monies not linked to the
holding of
reserves
were to
proliferate, the fact that the government pays by check and requires
all tax
payments to be
by bank
check would not be sufficient to maintain the effectiveness of monetary
policy
either.
Proliferation
of Nonbank Credit. An entirely different trend, but one that likewise
threatens
the relevance of the central bank’s position as monopoly supplier of
reserves,
is the
declining
role of banks (and other depository intermediaries) in advancing credit
to the
nonfinancial
economy. Under the “credit view” of monetary policy, banks are
important not
because
they create deposits but because they make loans. Money creation is
merely what
happens
on the other side of the balance sheet when a bank extends credit. But
because
the
deposits
thus created are subject to reserve requirements, this process too
generates a
demand for
the
reserves over which the central bank has a monopoly on supply. If the
lender is
not a bank,
however,
so that the liabilities behind the loan are not deposits, then credit
creation
ordinarily
implies
no increase in the demand for reserves.
In the United
States
banks have been losing market share in the credit business ever since
World War
II. In 1950 the financial assets (mostly loans and securities
investments) of U.S.
commercial
banks represented 51% of the total assets of all U.S.
financial intermediaries. By
1975
banks’ market share had fallen to 38%. Today it is just 24%. Including
savings
institutions
and
credit unions, which also come within the scope of the central bank’s
reserve
requirements,.15
the
combined share of the U.S.
credit market accounted for by depository institutions was 65% in
1950, but
only 30% today. The difference over time primarily represents the rapid
advance
of
pension
funds, insurance companies and mutual funds — none of which hold
reserves (in
the
sense of
balances with the central bank) against their liabilities. In
consequence,
economists’
empirical
research on questions pertaining to the “credit view” of monetary
policy mostly
focuses
not on
aggregate business need for credit but only on those firms that are
“bank
dependent” by
virtue of
being too small, or otherwise insufficiently known, to borrow from
nonbank
lenders via
the
securities market.
There are
two reasons, apart from simple extrapolation of past experience, for
thinking
that the
trend toward diminished importance of banks and other depository
intermediaries
is likely
to
continue. First, advances in data processing technology, and therefore
in the
availability of
information,
are continually reducing the prevalence of the informational
asymmetries that
give
bank-type
“relationship” lending an advantage over “arm’s length” lending in
securities
markets.
Individual
households seeking home mortgage financing, for example, no longer have
to sit
through
extensive interviews with bank loan officers. In uncomplicated cases,
which
represent the
majority
of home financing, supplying standard information on line — information
that
potential
lenders
can in turn readily verify on line — is sufficient to produce a
competitive
loan offer within
24 hours.
And
second, even for those households and firms that remain “bank
dependent,”
securities
markets
have now advanced to the point where the bank that investigates the
borrower’s
creditworthiness,
originates the loan, and services the credit relationship, no longer
needs to
hold.16
the loan
in its own portfolio. Instead, today most kinds of bank-originated
loans are
regularly
sold to
firms that package them into aggregated portfolios of similar credits,
which in
turn stand
as
collateral behind securities owned and traded by market investors — the
pension
funds and
insurance
companies and mutual funds that are taking over market share from
banks, as
well as
households
who buy these securities directly on their own account.
In the United
States,
home mortgage lending was the first sector of the credit markets to
be
securitized in this way, under government sponsorship, and by now more
than
half (by dollar
volume)
of all home mortgages outstanding are held by securities market
investors
rather than by
the banks
or savings institutions that made the loans. Similarly, nearly
two-thirds of
government-sponsored
student
loans, all originated by banks, are securitized. But securitization has
only
just
begun to
gain momentum in other sectors of what until recently was primarily the
banks’
market.
Today 28%
of consumer credit, 17% of commercial mortgages, and 11% of firms’
trade credit
is
securitized.
There is now even a small but rapidly growing market in which banks are
securitizing
their
ordinary commercial and industrial loans.
The
import of securitization in this context is simply that it severs even
the
bank-originated
component
of the economy’s credit extension process from any direct relation to
the
central
bank’s system of required reserves. A loan extended by a bank and held
on the
bank’s
balance
sheet is financed by deposits, which are subject to reserve
requirements. (In
many
countries
not all kinds of deposits, and not all forms of nondeposit bank
liabilities, are
subject to
reserve
requirements; but this only makes the existing linkage weaker.) The
same loan
extended
by the
same bank but securitized and sold to a nonbank investor is financed by
that
investor’s.17
liabilities
or net worth, neither of which is subject to reserve requirements. From
the
perspective
of the
“credit view,” therefore, the central bank’s monopoly over the supply
of
reserves is
irrelevant.
Private
Bank Clearing Mechanisms. In some countries today — for example, in the
U.K.
and Canada,
and increasingly so among small banks in
the United States
since required reserve
ratios
were reduced in 1990 and 1991 — many banks’ motivation for holding
reserve
balances
with the
central bank actually has little or nothing to do with reserve
requirements. These
reserves
are, rather, a necessary means of settling interbank transactions
through the
central
bank’s
clearing mechanism. On any given day, a bank may have more checks
presented for
payment
than checks deposited. If its reserve balance is insufficient to cover
the
difference, its
account
at the central bank will be overdrawn at the end of the day, in which
case most
central
banks
will assess a penalty of one form or other. If the central bank does
not allow
“daylight
overdrafts,”
the bank must similarly maintain an adequate reserve balance to cover
such
contingencies
even on an intra day basis.
The role
played by the interbank clearing mechanism in creating a demand for
reserves is
far
removed from either the “money view” or the “credit view” of monetary
policy —
or any
other
standard textbook story, for that matter. (There is some ultimate
connection to
the “money
view,”
since the use of bank money in executing day-to-day transactions is
what
creates the need
for a
clearing mechanism in the first place.) But nonetheless, and in just
the same
way, it gives the
central
bank the leverage to move large markets with tiny operations. The main
point is
once.18
again
that these clearing needs impose on banks, and therefore indirectly on
the
economy as a
whole, a need
for what the central bank is a monopolist over.
But
competition can threaten this monopoly too. Private clearing mechanisms
like
the
CHIPS
network, and other privately maintained interbank netting systems like
those
studied in the
1990
report of the ad hoc BIS committee (the Lamfalussy Report), potentially
represent just such
threats.
In a way that is conceptually parallel to nonfinancial businesses’
incentive to
introduce
private
monies in order to capture for themselves some of the profit that
otherwise
accrues to the
banks,
private clearing mechanisms like CHIPS offer banks the ability to
economize on
either
charges
paid or collateral required in central banks’ real-time gross
settlement
systems, like the
Federal
Reserve System’s “Fedwire” or the European countries’ systems that are
now
linked by
the
E.U.’s TARGET system. The crucial question is who is best situated to
be the
provider of
financial
network services. Central banks have some advantages in this regard,
but their
superiority
is not unambiguous. And, again by analogy to the use of private monies,
private
settlement
systems can be (and are) used along with the systems provided by
central banks.
Most of
the discussion of private clearing mechanisms to date has focused on
the risks
that
they present
for a breakdown of the payments system in the event of default, and as
of today
that
prospect
is certainly the more serious concern. Moreover, so far even these
private
mechanisms
for
clearing interbank accounts rely, at the end of the process, on
transfers of
central bank money.
CHIPS,
for example, is a net settlement system in the sense that it nets
participating
banks’
respective
claims on one another within the day. But at the end of each day,
remaining
claims on
CHIPS
that have not netted out are settled using the Fedwire. Except for the
intraday
netting,.19
therefore,
banks participating in CHIPS still need reserves at the central bank to
settle
their
payments.
But this
need not be so. A private mechanism like CHIPS could evolve into a
system of
purely
bilateral transfers among private banks analogous to the settlement
method now
used by
European
countries’ central banks, which do not maintain clearing balances at
the E.C.B.
Another
possibility would be transfers of deposits at a single private bank
that all
the others
agreed to
use. A quarter-century or so into the future, therefore, it is also
readily
conceivable that
one or
more of these private clearing mechanisms may sufficiently erode banks’
need
for central
bank
reserves as to undermine the relevance of the central bank’s monopoly.
If so,
it would also
undermine
the central bank’s ability to carry out an effective monetary policy.
Explicitly
International Dimensions
One of
the most consistent developments in the monetary sphere in the last
quarter of
the
twentieth
century has been the increasing irrelevance of nation-state boundaries.
The
easiest way
to see
that this is so is simply to note that the number of national
currencies has
not kept pace
with the
proliferation of independent countries. One of the few safe predictions
about
the world
25 years
in the future is probably that there will be more countries but fewer
currencies.
The
disappearing relevance of national borders in this context also prompts
several
lines of
speculation
(and each is no more than that) about what the future may bring. Each
stems
from
realizing
that the wave of currency consolidation that is now in progress, and
likely to
continue
for the
foreseeable future, is mostly not an attempt to rearrange the world
into “optimal
currency.20
areas” in
economists’ usual sense. In some settings, like Western
Europe, the motivation is
instead
to exploit economic unification, in this instance monetary unification,
as the
leading edge
of
political unification. In other settings, especially among smaller
countries
and in the developing
world,
the motivation is to mitigate the speculative instabilities that many
central
banks
increasingly
face in a world where currencies are convertible, capital flows freely,
and
market
participants
in the aggregate (and even some individually) bulk large compared to
the assets
at the
central
bank’s disposal.
Especially
in the wake of the East Asian financial crisis of 1997-98, much of the
discussion
of the
implications of globalization of financial markets has emphasized the
problems
posed for a
central
bank of a small country that is trying to maintain a specific chosen
value of
its currency.
But for
this purpose currency policy and monetary policy are the same. Whether
the
central bank
has the
resources to withstand speculation against the exchange value of its
currency
is really the
same
question as whether the central bank has the ability to control the
short-term
interest rate on
marketable
obligations denominated in its currency.
Rapid
advances in electronic technology, especially in communications, not
only have
brought
many more investors into the international markets (some on their own
account,
some via
mutual
funds) but also have created a much greater degree of coherence in the
attitudes and
portfolio
behavior of investors who remain physically dispersed. As a result, one
central
bank
after
another, among economies that are not large but not tiny either, has
found
itself
overwhelmed.
Thus far the central banks of the larger industrialized countries have
not
faced
serious
inability to control their short-term interest rates. But as financial
globalization advances,.21
this
prospect too is hardly impossible. If so, the central banks of the
large
countries would, in all
likelihood,
seek to change the rules governing global financial markets in some way
designed to
maintain
their ability to carry out monetary policy.
The
tendency for central banks of the larger countries to resist
surrendering their
monetary
policy
powers to the forces of global market speculation is likely to be even
greater
because of
some of
the lessons learned from the East Asian crisis. Benign assumptions
about the
workings of
speculative
markets notwithstanding, it was simply not true that the countries that
got
into
difficulty
were exclusively those that were highly indebted, or were running large
budget
deficits
or
current account deficits, or had made other obvious policy mistakes, or
where
transparency of
financial
dealings and the rule of law more generally were especially weak. What
was
striking
about the
crisis as it rolled through one country and then another was the degree
of
apparent
arbitrariness
in investors’ behavior. Even the explanations offered after the fact,
for what
had
happened
to any specific country, often tended to point to national vices that,
only a
few years
before,
the international investment community had largely hailed as virtues.
Small
countries have little ability to alter the rules of international
finance in
order to
protect
themselves from arbitrarily destabilizing speculation. Their only
choice is to
participate in
global
markets or not. Large countries, however — and especially the large
countries
acting in
concert —
have broader latitude in this respect, and if they feel threatened they
are
likely to use it.
Just what
changes in the rules they would most likely seek is harder to say,
although the
surprising
abruptness
with which the idea of capital controls has gone from being a taboo
subject in
polite
conversation
to a focus of open-minded inquiry is perhaps suggestive. (Indeed, the
sheer
number.22
of
recently published books hailing the wisdom of the judgments made by
unfettered
capital
markets
may itself be a marker that the tide of informed opinion is beginning
to turn
in a different
direction.)
Here too,
the likely outcome in many cases is a continued race between regulators
and
innovators,
with the advantage over time probably on the side of the innovators. To
the
extent
that
countries act in concert, however, they may gain an advantage in this
regard.
One of the
reasons
for the failure of many past attempts at the national level to bring
certain
classes of
transactions
with the central bank’s regulatory (and reserve requirement) sphere is
market
participants’
ability to move the endangered transactions “off shore.” No doubt
regulatory
havens
will
always exist, but the more countries were to coordinate their efforts
in this
dimension the
more
isolated, and therefore subject to potential discrimination, the
remaining
unregulated
domiciles
would become.
Globalization
of financial markets also has implications for the ability of central
banks to
maintain
the relevance of their monopoly over the supply of reserves — and hence
effectiveness
of their
monetary policy actions — through their operation of the payments
clearing
mechanism.
International
markets magnify the potential ability of private clearing mechanisms to
compete
with
public
ones. Moreover, currency substitution opens the way for what amounts to
competition
among
national clearing mechanisms, even if each is maintained by a different
country’s central
bank in
its own currency. As firms and households, and therefore banks, use
currencies
other
than that
of their own country, the country’s geographical space becomes less
relevant
for
indicating
over what financial transactions and nonfinancial economic behavior the
central
bank’s.23
actions
have efficacy. (A parallel process is the use of “units of account”
other than
a country’s
currency
to denominate wages and other payments.) Hence individual central banks
may
have
influence
over geographically dispersed sectors of economic activity, and
specific
economic
disturbances
like productivity shocks or oil price shocks may likewise exert their
effect on
geographically
dispersed sectors rather than recognizable national economies.
Finally,
what implications follow from the trend toward currency consolidation
per se?
Living
with a common currency means living under the same monetary policy, and
hence
the same
interest
rates and exchange rates. When different countries or different parts
of the
same country
have a
common currency, therefore, it is highly likely that from time to time
the
monetary policy
that will
be best for one will be quite unsuitable for the other. This phenomenon
is
thoroughly
familiar
among the disparate regional economies within the United States.
(The most obvious
example
is what happened to Texas
in the mid 1980s, when the regional economy was depressed
because
of falling oil prices but U.S.
monetary policy remained highly restrictive as part of the
continuing
effort to restore nationwide price stability.) There is no reason not
to expect
the same
kind of
outcome from time to time among, for example, the member countries of
the
European
Union.
As is
well known from the standard theory of optimal currency areas, however,
under
the
right
conditions even countries or regions with highly dissimilar economies
can
happily share a
common
monetary policy. The usual list of such conditions includes price
flexibility,
labor
mobility,
and the ability and willingness to make cross-country, or cross-region,
fiscal
transfers.
Of these,
neither price flexibility nor labor mobility seems likely to increase
sharply
within the.24
immediate
future (although each is really the subject for another paper). What
remains,
therefore, is the possibility of fiscal transfers.
It is
extremely doubtful that the countries that are now pursuing currency
consolidation in reaction to financial or economic distress have any
prospect
of coupling it with any kind of serious international fiscal transfer
system.
If Argentina goes ahead and abandons the peso in favor of the U.S.
dollar, for
example, it presumably will not do so in the expectation of
compensation from
the
United States any time the Federal Open Market
Committee chooses a monetary policy that may be optimal for the U.S. economy but injurious to Argentina.
Countries that are consolidating their
currencies
as an aspect of desired further political unification, however — like
the
European Union — are a different story.
Because
of the substantial economic heterogeneity that prevails across the
participating countries, Europe’s new
monetary
union is very likely to prove unstable in its current form.
Much
speculation, recently diminished by the euphoria surrounding the euro’s
successful introduction (to date only as a unit of account), has
focused on
whether some crisis or other may drive one or more of the union’s
eleven member
countries to abandon the project, and if so, just what that would mean.
A more
likely outcome, however, is that the pressures of such a crisis —or of
repeated
crises — would force the creation of a broader union, importantly
including
coordination of fiscal policies across the member countries (beyond the
existing obligation under the Maastricht Treaty to limit government
deficits to
3% of national income) as well as fiscal transfers among them..25
The
logical starting place for such fiscal transfers would be
lender-of-last-resort
policy and deposit insurance, both of which arise as natural adjuncts
of
monetary policy even though they are essentially fiscal functions, and
both of
which (especially lender-of-last-resort actions) may be easier to
introduce
politically because they arise in the context of actual or threatened
financial
crises rather than as an aspect of ordinary ongoing circumstances.
Beyond lies
the entire range of
intergovernmental
revenue sharing schemes, as well as personal tax and transfer systems,
that
would enable a member country enjoying a monetary policy that is right
for its
economic needs to help ease the burden on another member country that
is forced
to accept the same monetary policy even if its needs are sharply
different.
Just how far the European Union will go along this route, if that is
indeed the
probable outcome, is no doubt a matter of the specific time horizon in
question.
But the thought that monetary union may in time force the evolution of
a
deeper, more fundamentally political level of unification is probably
not
inconsistent with what the euro’s original architects had in mind.
Concluding
Remarks
It is
important to be clear that the threat outlined here to central banks’
ability
to conduct monetary policy, arising from any or all of several ways in
which
their monopoly over the supply of reserves might become irrelevant,
applies to
central banks’ ability to influence prices in the nonfinancial economy
no less
than production and employment. Hence even those who believe that
central banks
should not concern themselves with real outcomes anyway (as a stricter
interpretation
of the European Central Bank’s mission than that given above would
imply)
cannot.26 simply sweep the issue aside. If the central bank cannot
affect
interest rates — in other words, the prices of financial assets — in
its
country’s financial markets, because borrowing and lending in those
markets
proceed independently of whatever amount of reserves it chooses to
supply, it
cannot affect the price level of goods and services in the nonfinancial
economy
either. Whether, and to what extent, the appropriate response to this
loss of
monetary policy potency is to be regretted — and, where possible,
resisted —
depends on fundamental economic presumptions that lie well beyond the
scope of
this paper. At the most basic level, economic theory provides no clear
answer
to what would determine an economy’s price level if what its
inhabitants used
as money depended entirely on their own ability and willingness to
innovate,
without effective restraint from the central bank or some other
designated
authority. Especially in light of many industrialized economies’
success in
achieving price stability over the last two
decades,
and the important role that most observers assign to these countries’
central
banks in bringing about this achievement, the prospect of diminished
central
bank effectiveness will not be reassuring.
Similar
considerations arise with respect to output and employment. There is no
lack of
theories to describe how central bank actions can affect nonfinancial
economic
outcomes, but the quantitative importance of actual monetary policies
in
accounting for observed business fluctuations remains a subject of
empirical
debate. Those who discount that importance (in the limit, who believe
that
monetary policy is “neutral” with respect to nonfinancial outcomes)
need not be
apprehensive, at least on this ground, about the trends identified
here. But
for those who believe that monetary policy is a major influence
underlying the
movement of output and.27 employment — for example, who credit the
favorable economic
performance in the United
States in recent years in substantial
part
to the Federal Reserve System — the prospect of diminished central bank
potency
is a proper object of concern. Whether, and to what extent, to favor
aggressive
regulatory changes to preserve the economic relevance of the central
bank’s
monopoly over the supply of reserves turns on the same set of issues.
Of
course, central banks will still always be able to announce what they
want
interest rates, or inflation, or output and employment to be. Private
economic
agents, and especially participants in the financial markets, will
continue to
pay attention. But without the ability to implement a policy with some
independent means of making those intentions come about, such
pronouncements will
be just that. With nothing behavioral to back them up, they will have
about the
same force over events as Wang Wei-shao’s splendid poems.
|